Uncategorized

Pseudo Innovation

Screen Shot 2014-08-01 at 2.06.25 PMFew people know that new prescription drugs have a 1 in 5 chance of causing serious reactions after they have been approved. That is why expert physicians recommend not taking new drugs for at least five years unless patients have first tried better-established options and need to. Faster reviews advocated by the industry-funded public regulators increase the risk of serious harm to 1 in 3. Yet most drugs they approve are found to have few offsetting clinical advantages over existing ones.

Systematic reviews of hospital charts by expert teams have found that even properly prescribed drugs (aside from misprescribing, overdosing, or self-prescribing) cause about 1.9 million hospitalizations a year. Another 840,000 hospitalized patients given drugs have serious adverse reactions for a total of 2.74 million. Further, the expert teams attributed as many deaths to the drugs as people who die from stroke. A policy review done at the Edmond J. Safra Center for Ethics at Harvard University concluded that prescription drugs are tied with stroke as the 4th leading cause of death in the United States. The European Commission estimates that adverse reactions from prescription drugs cause 200,000 deaths; so together, about 328,000 patients in the US and Europe die from prescription drugs each year. The FDA does not acknowledge these facts and instead gathers a small fraction of the cases.

Perhaps this is “the price of progress”? For example, about 170 million Americans take prescription drugs, and many benefit from them. For some, drugs keep them alive. If we suppose they all benefit, then 2.7 million people have a severe reactions, it’s only about 1.5 percent – the price of progress?

However, independent reviews over the past 35 years have found that only 11-15 percent of newly approved drugs have significant clinical advantages over existing, better-known drugs. While these contribute to the large medicine chest of effective drugs developed over the decades, the 85-89 percent with little or no clinical advantage flood the market. Of the additional $70 billion spent on drugs since 2000 in the U.S. (and another $70 billion abroad), about four-fifths has been spent on purchasing these minor new variations rather than on the really innovative drugs.

In a recent decade, independent reviewers concluded that only 8 percent of 946 new products were clinically superior, down from 11-15 percent in previous decades. (See Figure) Only 2 were breakthroughs and another 13 represented a real therapeutic advance.

Spokesmen for the pharmaceutical industry point out that therapeutically similar drugs have advantages. First, physicians need some choice within a therapeutic class because some patients do not respond well to a given drug. This is true, but after about three choices, there is little evidence to justify a 4th , 5th, or 6th in a class.

Second, a sub-group of patients may benefit from a new drug that seems similar. This may be true or not, and we need to identify that sub-group so the effectiveness of the drug can be tested on them. The point of testing drugs for approval is to identify which patients might benefit and see if they do, not to assume that some patients somewhere might.

Third, industry spokespersons argue that every incremental development contributes to larger improvements. This might be true, but most significant clinical advances occur through major discoveries. Yet most major scientific discoveries do not significantly improve patients’ health and some may prove deadly. Silvio Garattini, a leader in pharmacological research told me, “When a major discovery actually helps patients, we feel very lucky.”

The Hidden Business Model of R&D 

Flooding the market with hundreds of minor variations seems to be the hidden business model of drug companies, to exploit patent and other IP protections for profits, not for significant advances for patient health. Looking back, Jerry Avorn, an authority on pharmacoepidemiology, wrote “Laws designed to encourage and protect meaningful innovation had been turned into a system that rewarded trivial pseudo-innovation even more profitably than important discoveries.”

Despite fewer superior drugs, Marc-André Gagnon has shown that sales and profits soared. Net return on revenues (ROR) rose from about 10 percent in the 1970s to 12.5 percent by 1990, to 16 percent by 2000, to 19 percent in 2010. Pharmaceutical ROR has increased from about 2.5 times to 3.2 times the return for the Fortune 500 giants, largely by raising prices and getting more physicians to prescribe more drugs.

Risk for the major companies is much less than claimed for several reasons. First, they spread risk over many projects. Second, once inflators and public subsidies are taken out, net research costs are a fraction of the $1-5 billion per new drug claimed, and big companies largely invest after the public and others have paid for the high risks of research to discover new drugs. As new drugs enter clinical trials, their risks are just 1 in 5. Third, companies cut losses by stopping development of drugs whose profit potential is not as high as they want. We never will know how many beneficial drugs never get approved because companies dropped them for insufficient profit potential.

Over the past 35 years, this hidden business model based on marketing power and prowess more than innovation has caused an epidemic of harmful side effects. Given estimates that about 30 adverse reactions occur for every one that leads to hospitalization, about 81 million adverse reactions are experienced by the 170 million Americans taking drugs. The elderly and those taking multiple drugs experience more than others. Most are medically minor, like muscle aches, gastro-intestinal discomforts, slower reactions, or sleepiness. But they reduce productivity and cause many falls and road accidents.

The Trial-Journal Pipeline

The pharmaceutical industry refers constantly to its “R&D pipeline” of new drugs under development. But there is a second, parallel pipeline – the trial-journal pipeline – that produces biased medical information on scores of new drugs to make them look scientifically more effective and safer than they prove to be in actual clinical practice.

The Trial-Journal Pipeline consists of randomized clinical trials designed with the marketing departments to produce evidence that their drugs are more effective and safer than unbiased trials would show. Commercially funded clinical trials are at least 2.5 times more likely to favor the sponsor’s drug than non-commercially funded trials.

The FDA accepts these biased trials and uses them to approve drugs. Congress strongly supports having companies fund the division that reviews new drugs rather than having the FDA be a publicly funded, independent reviewer and regulator. Financially, the FDA is an agent of the pharmaceutical industry, and it plays a major role in expanding markets for more people to take more drugs.

For the journal part of the pipeline, pharmaceutical companies retain teams of statisticians, science editors, and science writers to select which results will go into the medical literature and which will not. They switch end points and other details in the trial data submitted to the FDA so that physicians read twice-biased medical articles that understate risks of harm and overstate benefits. Negative results are much less likely to be published than positive results, and companies publish positive results more than once, a further bias that distorts clinical practice and guidelines as well the medical knowledge that underlies it.

Marc Rodwin concludes, “scholarly studies have revealed that drug firms design trials that skew the result and that they distort the evidence by selective reporting or biased interpretation.”

This published literature goes into clinical guidelines and protocols. Originally, they were established to provide an unbiased, evidence-based way to practice good medicine. ButLisa Cosgrove and Emily Wheeler document how they have become “essentially marketing tools for drug companies.” They create “the potential to expose many patients to harm from unnecessary treatment or from treatment that is not evidence-based.” The situation is worse because the evidence is twice-biased and corrupts medical science. Companies then employ what Sergio Sismondo describes as “a two-step model of influence by hiring and otherwise enrolling some physicians and researchers who will, in turn influence many others” to prescribe the new, patented drugs.

New FDA policies to get more drugs reviewed faster so that they can reach patients sooner in fact mean that drugs are approved with less evidence of being safe or effective. A systematic study of shortened reviews found that each 10-month reduction results in an 18 percent increase in serious adverse reactions, an 11percent increases in hospitalizations, and a 7.2 percent increase in deaths. This study complements the one that found the risk of serious adverse reactions occurring after fast approvals increases from 1 in 5, to 1 in 3. Congress and the public do not seem aware of this and other evidence that new policies that increase profits for drug companies put patients are greater serious risk.

In response to drug disasters like Vioxx, which experts say caused about 120,000 traumatic cardiovascular events and 40,000 deaths, Congress and the FDA have set up monitoring and safety systems. But a review of results so far found little evidence they are identifying serious risks or altering prescribing practices.

One key reform that would make new drugs safer and more effective would be to require that the FDA have evidence that new drugs are clinically effective. A top team at the London School of Economics concludes that requiring comparative evidence before approval informs all decision makers of the relative merits of new treatments. Also, it “could encourage manufacturers to concentrate on the development of new drugs in therapeutic areas with few or no alternatives.” While changing legislation is difficult, the FDA could use its administrative powers and guidelines to get more evidence that new drugs actually help patients before reviewing them.

Figure:

Prescrire Fig Bars  2002-2011

 

Donald Light is a fellow at Harvard’s Edward J. Safra Institute for Ethics. He blogs at Harvard Law School’s Bill of Health, where this post first appeared.

5 replies »

  1. @Cindy I like your third Comment basically you can’t just produce a drug and let that drug be used by the community, all we know is that every individual has different kinds of body and unlike reactions to chemicals and other things that would harm their bodies. First of all, if a substance/drug is used without any professional notice, then it would affect the body without the user knowing and how far it will go some are allergic to things like seafood or other kind of product so, if the drug is made with fish oil you know what will happen and that chemical reaction will definitely kill that patient accidently. Some facts like death by prescription actually killed 7,000 people annually, which is quite alarming, but health administration won’t do anything about that and blame the pharmaceutical companies for giving the wrong medicine. And these things aren’t published on magazines or TV as it will lower the credibility of doctors who have done and killed innocent lives on his/her handwriting.
    Missouri substance recovery

  2. Thoughtful and well-cited article that adds to the calls for action. I have 3 comments:
    1. Subtle differences in drugs, between brands that are incremental and between brands and generics, do make a difference for some folks. I would propose that those folks that need the particular brand be recruited for follow-up, at least through open source surveys. I have 2 family members in which these are important, and I’m learning of more and more when I speak of these folks. When a patient is compliant and adherent to the dosing instructions/lifestyle changes and still runs into adverse events, that info should automatically go into a data repository (with the patient’s permission). Then, the data of adverse events should be open-source so that data experts can comb the data for attributes and publish the findings. This would help everyone, including the drug companies.
    2. When a truly innovative drug is released (such as the new one for HepC) then it should be met with innovative payment schemes. I’ve written about possibilities before, and I’ve been vocal about one such contract, the Cigna-Merck contract for diabetes, because it wasn’t entirely built on rebates for Januvia, but escalated the rebates across the diabetic population if adherence improved, regardless of the drug the patient was taking . You can read more at http://www.cyndynayer.com/nayer-cigna-merck-outcomes-based-vbbd/ The goal is to create a contract that does not reimburse the entire amount in the first year, but takes 2-3 years to study the population, understand the adherence attributes of the population, and rewards the total stakeholders for submitting data (health plan, Rx, provider, patient,…).
    3. To go far out onto a limb here, perhaps “me-too” drugs should be preliminarily reviewed on the number of adverse effects they address from other same-class drug regimens. What this means: if patients were asked to review drugs at start, at 6 months, at 1 year, and every year thereafter, again, we would have a data base of changes over time and gaps that need to be filled. Then, those drugs that met that challenge would /could be fast-tracked.

    My goal here is to call for system-innovation in accepting the innovative compounds that are coming out. I’m interested in your thoughts.

  3. Yes, there is much to discuss in here. Many of the points you raise are valid issues and worthy of debate here

    But the tone of this piece tends to exaggeration and dramatization. Your opening, for example:

    Most people don”t know that new prescription drugs have a 1 in 5 chance of causing serious harm. I’m terrified. But wait – what does “serious” harm entail? Are my limbs going to fall off? Are my internal organs going to stop functioning? Am I going to develop cancer? Or am I going to experience nausea and vomiting?

    And expert doctors tell me I should wait 5 years, I had no idea there was a consensus – I’m depressed and confused. I had no idea “expert” doctors felt this way, clearly this must be some sort of conspiracy on the part of the mainstream media

    I’m not even going to ask where you found this statistic

  4. Great article.

    One of the many things hidden from the view of the consuming public is the amount of work that drug companies and their armies of consultants do to position incremental benefits (i.e., fewer patients experience a particular side effect) as dramatic therapeutic advances that can encourage consumer demand and/or physician willingness to prescribe. They can also help to ensure favorable placement on formularies, which is critical to product success. Companies are told routinely to play down absolute risks (e.g., the number of patients experiencing migraines with drug X went down from 20/1,000 to 10/1,000) and focus on relative data (risk of migraine dropped 50%!), which is much more impressive and often misinterpreted by consumers and clinicians alike.