By
“It seems that John McCain may have stolen some of the fire that Democrats traditionally wield on health issues by making cost control his top priority, rather than universal coverage.” -Rob Cunningham, “Health Affairs” May/June 2008
Last week, the bold proposal for health care reform that Dr. Ezekiel Emanuel outlines in Healthcare, Guaranteed drew high praise from the American Prospect’s Ezra Klein. As Klein described it:
Emanuel’s Guaranteed Health Care Access Plan maps out “a total transformation of the system. It does not build on the inefficiencies of the current structure, preserving them in amber for the next generation.”
Rather than expanding on the dysfunctional system that we have today, Emanuel, who is the director of bioethics at NIH (and brother to politician Rahm Emanuel), is calling for structural reform. This is what makes his proposal both brave and fresh.
But Emanuel’s plan isn’t just exciting; it’s practical. As usual, Klein cuts to the heart of the matter: “The big deal, he explains is cost control. In health care, cost control is everything.”
“At the current rate, health care will grow to 30 percent of GDP by 2030,” he continues. “That’s money — in the trillions — that can’t be spent on other things, either progressive priorities like universal pre-k or personal priorities like buying a home and taking a vacation. And what are we getting for the amount we spend? . . experts estimate that 20 cents to 50 cents of every dollar spent on care is wasted on unnecessary or ineffective treatments. It’s a tragically bad deal . . . Arguably nothing more progressive could happen in our country than for health care to get cheaper, so families and the government have more money for other priorities. There’s nothing progressive about wasting 20% to 50% of the dollars spent on health care.”
As Congressional Budget Director Peter Orszag recently pointed out, we’re facing a crisis.
“We need to weed out the treatments that don’t improve outcomes,” Orszag declared. “Health Care is the least efficient sector of our economy” . . . and one “unexpected effect” is that the price of health care has been “driving up the cost of tuition at state universities because state support for Medicaid has been crowding out state support for higher education.”
That is why I believe that progressives must begin talking about the high cost of care, and how we need to wring the waste out of the system to make truly effective, high quality care affordable for everyone. Don’t let the conservatives dominate the debate about spending. If they do, they’ll take the conversation in the wrong direction.
What Emanuel’s Plan Offers
But first, let me re-cap, in a paragraph, what I wrote last month here and here about Emanuel’s proposal.
Emmanuel would offer free, high quality health care to all Americans. No premiums. No deductibles. Low co-pays. Rather than depending on an employer for health insurance, every American would receive a government voucher that he could trade in for a health care plan of his choice. Insurers would be tightly regulated. Every plan would have to offer the same comprehensive benefits –- coverage that is more generous than Medicare’s and more comprehensive than what 85 percent of all employers offer their employees.
Because no money would be changing hands, insurers could not charge customers more if they suffer from “pre-existing conditions.” (If a company winds up with a disproportionate number of sick or elderly patients, the government would pay the insurer more on a risk-adjusted basis.) Ultimately, insurers would have to compete on quality, not on price, by providing patients with a network of hospitals and doctors where outcomes are better, errors are rarer, and patients find what patients want: competence and kindness.
How the Guaranteed HealthCare Access Plan Controls Costs
Emanuel’s plan reins in health care inflation in three ways.
First, it mends a hopelessly fragmented system. “Integration is crucial for cost control, Klein observes. “Today “800+ private insurers, all operating in their own little fiefdoms, forge hundreds of different contracts with thousands of different employers and millions of individuals. You can’t effectively regulate it because you can’t get your hands around it. Add in Medicare, Medicaid, S-CHIP, the VA, the IHS, and all the other mop-up plans, and you’re left with a dizzyingly broken and diffuse system.
The administrative costs of such a system are huge. By removing the employer as middle man, Emanuel shows that his plan could save roughly $120 billion a year. Moreover, over time, Emanuel would fold Medicare, Medicaid and SCHIP into the Guaranteed HealthCare Access Plan, further unifying and streamlining the system. (From the outset, anyone who wanted to leave one of those programs to join the new Plan would be welcome.)
Insurers also would save because they wouldn’t have to market their plans to millions of employers. Instead they deal only with 12 Regional Boards that oversee the insurers — and make sure that they are following the rules. Because insurers would be competing on quality, they would have an incentive to sink any administrative savings into investments that reduce errors in their hospital networks. For instance, they might plow some of the savings into the electronic medical records that they would need in order to report patient outcomes to the Regional Boards.
Secondly the Plan sets up an independent Institute for Technology and Outcomes Assessment that would compare the effectiveness of various drugs, devices and procedures. (Earlier this week, I explained how comparative effectiveness research works.)
Today, because we have so little data comparing different treatments and interventions, physicians find themselves at the mercy of what manufacturers choose to tell them about their products. Doctors are “flooded with hundreds of publications on cancer alone,” Emanuel and health care economist Victor Fuchs note in a recent issue of Fuchs originally collaborated with Emanuel on creating the voucher approach over a period of five years. )
But without head-to-head comparisons, they conclude, “it is extremely difficult for doctors to judiciously incorporate new data into their practices.”
Meanwhile pharmaceutical companies spend more than $7 billion annually — about $10,000 per physician -– on marketing aimed at doctors. As Emanuel and Fuchs point out: “Companies can selectively highlight favorable studies from the mass of research, confident that there are few comparative effectiveness data for physicians to put the marketers’ desired conclusions into a proper context.”
By contrast, an Institute for Technology Assessment would give doctors the unbiased information that they need in the form of “guidelines” (not rules) for best practice,” outlining which treatments are likely to be most effective for particular patients.
Third, the Institute would be insulated from both Congress and the lobbyists who promote the most lucrative products because the entire Plan would be funded by a dedicated 10 percent Value-Added Tax that could be used only for health care. Because revenue from the tax would grow with normal inflation in the cost of consumer goods and services, the Plan would not have to go back to Congress each year for appropriations.
Revenue from the VAT would be the only funding available to the Guaranteed Health Care Access Plan, and as a result, Klein points out: the VAT would “act essentially as a global budget. It is extremely powerful cost control. If people want more expansive insurance options in the basic plan, they have to elect politicians who will raise the VAT tax.”
Few politicians would want to vote for a tax hike. As a result, the VAT will act as an automatic cap on health care spending.
How the VAT Would Be Off-Set by Higher Wages and Lower Taxes
But would Americans sit still for a brand new 10% national sales tax on everything they buy? This “will unsettle a lot of folks,” Klein acknowledges. “This is particularly true because people believe, wrongly, that their employers pay for their health care. In fact, as research by Emanuel shows, that money is coming out of their wages. But folks don’t know that, and the necessary work has not been done to convince them of it.”
In truth, benefits are part of what employers call “total compensation.” When they pay more for health care benefits, they pay lower wages. This helps explain why wages have stagnated over the past three decades.
As Emanuel and Fuchs observed not long ago in the Chicago Tribune:
“This cost-wage trade-off is usually well hidden from employers and workers, but many studies show that it is a painful reality for average Americans. For instance, over the last 30 years, health-insurance premiums have increased by 300 percent after adjustment for inflation. During that time, after-tax corporate profits per employee have increased 200 percent, while workers’ average hourly earnings, adjusted for inflation, decreased by 4 percent. Rather than coming out of corporate profits, the increasing cost of health care has resulted in relatively flat wages for 30 years.”
If employers were no longer expected to pick up the check for health insurance, many would very gratefully give their employees raises equal to what they now pay toward premiums. If they didn’t, other employers surely would — and steal their most valuable employees.
Employers who offer health care benefits to workers earning more than $60,000 now contribute an average of $9,000 to $13,000 toward the cost of a family plan. Under Emanuel’s plan, those households could expect to receive a $9,000 to $13,000 pay hike—which would go a long way toward covering their new VAT taxes. And they would no longer have to pay anything toward their premiums.
In addition, because states would no longer be funding Medicaid and SCHIP, many Americans could look forward to cuts in state income taxes. Imagine a household that earns $150,000, spends $140,000 and pays $14,000 in VAT taxes. That family could reasonably expect a raise of roughly $11,000 and a break on their state income taxes of $3,000- or more—depending on where they live. Moreover, under Guaranteed Healthcare Access they could feel secure that they would never lose their insurance, even if they changed jobs.
Granted, employees on the bottom half of the income ladder would be less likely to receive raises equal to their benefits. In many cases, their employer probably doesn’t offer benefits. Or if he does, he makes a modest contribution to a skimpy plan that that doesn’t really protect the employee or his family.
But under the Guaranteed HealthCare Access Plan, a middle-class or lower-income family is assured comprehensive coverage at a very low price. Imagine a median income household that earns $50,000; assume that the family spends the entire $50,000, and pays $5,000 in VAT taxes. In return, they receive a insurance package worth roughly $13,000 (the average cost of employer-based family plan). This is why the VAT in Emanuel’s plan in not regressive—all of the revenues are re-distributed in the form of health benefits worth far more than the VAT taxes a low-income
“ Don’t Talk About Costs—You’re Helping the Conservatives”
As Klein points out, the necessary work has not been done to explain to Americans how runaway health care inflation has been hurting them by capping wages while draining state coffers of the dollars that states could be spending on social goods like higher education.
Why haven’t progressives done that work? Because too often, liberals reformers shy away from talking about the sky-high cost of health care in the U.S. — or how we’ll need to eliminate ineffective, sometimes harmful treatments in order to afford universal care.
I cannot tell you how many times I have heard intelligent, progressive reformers say: “We shouldn’t talk about costs and cost control. If you do that, you’re handing ammunition to the conservatives.” This is one reason why some don’t like Emanuel’s plan; it’s too candid about the fact that while millions of Americans receive too little health care, others receive too much in the form of redundant tests, ineffective, sometimes unproven procedures, and exorbitantly priced drugs and devices that are no better than their less expensive rivals.
The argument goes like this: “The conservatives will say that when liberals talk about ‘cost control’ what they are really talking about is RATIONING—government denying Americans the care they need. Don’t talk about ‘putting a brake on health care inflation,’” they counsel. “We’re a rich country. No one wants to hear that.”
So it’s left to the conservatives to talk about cutting costs, while progressives emphasize covering everyone.
Certainly that’s how the Los Angeles Times framed the debate last week, in an editorial which stated that the candidates are “giving voters a stark choice”: Obama “is calling for government to do more to address the nation’s ills,” while “McCain is embracing the traditional GOP faith in free-market solutions . . .”
The Obama proposal would “make coverage mandatory for children, expand federal subsidies for the uninsured and impose new funding requirements on employers.” This sounds generous, but one can’t help but wonder: won’t it be expensive?
McCain, on the other hand, “shuns that infusion of government money and authority” and “instead would rely on market competition to drive down costs.”
Message received: Obama wants to help the uninsured. McCain wants to “drive down costs.” But most Americans are not uninsured. Their biggest worry is the price of care. They are very concerned that, as premiums continue to spiral, insurance will soon become unaffordable, both for them and for their employer. They want to hear about how health care reform will lower costs.
The conservatives know exactly what they’re doing: “It seems that John McCain may have stolen some of the fire that Democrats traditionally wield on health issues by making cost control his top priority, rather than universal coverage,” Health Affairs deputy editor Rob Cunningham observed last month. Indeed, “McCain spokesman Doug Holtz-Eakin appeared to relish his role as a champion of fiscal discipline in a panel discussion with representatives of the Democratic candidates. “
In truth, Obama, like Emanuel, realizes that we cannot let health care spending continue to spiral. And he says so on his web page, “BARACK OBAMA’S PLAN FOR A HEALTHY AMERICA.”
Obama pulls no punches, acknowledging that “Though Americans spend almost twice as much per person as citizens of other industrialized countries, their health status is no better and by many measures actually worse . . .
“A growing body of research points to substantial opportunities to improve quality while reducing the costs of care,” Obama adds. “Some researchers estimate that as much as 30 percent of health care is not contributing materially to patient outcomes. Health care systems in many parts of the country deliver high quality care to the populations they serve at half of the costs of other equally renowned academic medical centers in other parts of the country.”
Obama makes it clear that spending more does not guarantee better care, and that we must address geographic variations in health care spending which have nothing to do with better health. There is no reason for Medicare to spend twice as much on a patient in a Boston hospital as it spends on a very similar patient at the Mayo Clinic in Rochester, Minnesota.
And, like Emanuel, he explicitly calls for “Comparative Effectiveness Reviews and Research, pointing out that while “The U.S. provides some of the best health care and most sophisticated medical technologies in the world, “ it does so at a cost that is making the effort to expand access to care ever more difficult.
“In order to be able to provide health care coverage for all,” Obama declares, we need to deliver the same quality of care at much lower cost. This is possible because there is considerable waste in our health care system . . . . One of the keys to eliminating waste and missed opportunities is to increase our investment in comparative effectiveness reviews and research. Comparative effectiveness studies provide crucial information about which drugs, devices and procedures are the best diagnostic and treatment options for individual patients. This information is developed by reviewing existing literature, analyzing electronic health care data, and conducting simple, real world studies of new technologies.”
Obama pledges to “establish an independent institute to guide reviews and research on comparative effectiveness, so that Americans and their doctors will have accurate and objective information to make the best decisions for their health and well-being.”
Yet some of Obama’s staunchest supporters insist that progressives shouldn’t call attention to their candidate’s plans to lower costs by weeding out the waste. They say Americans don’t want to hear about “Comparative Effectiveness” research.
Americans Already Know
I submit that while the lobbyists don’t want to hear about head-to-head comparisons, the American public recognize that in the institutionalized chaos that we call a health care system, everyone seems to be selling something. And the price tags are exorbitant. This makes many Americans more than a little wary.
We realize that as a nation, we are over-medicated. Virtually everyone knows an elderly person who is taking twenty or thirty pills. We realize that drug-makers, device-makers and some hospitals are gouging us, charging fantastic sums for bleeding-edge products and procedures that are no better than — and often riskier than — the older remedies that they have replaced.
Our newspapers are filled with tales of cutting-edge products being withdrawn from the marketplace — but only after dozens of deaths prove that they were never fully tested. Then there are the tales of surgeons taking kickbacks from medical device makers in return for using their most expensive (but not necessarily best) products.
In the New York Times, we read that each year, tens of thousands of patients undergo angioplasties that provide no benefit. The cover of Business Week asks “Do Cholesterol Drugs Do Any Good?” and the story inside warns that up to half of the patients taking these medications may be exposing themselves to risk without benefit.
How many of us have seen a loved one suffer through days and even weeks of unwanted and often unexplained end-of-life treatments?
Granted, as Emanuel observes, “US patients prefer high technology over high touch.” It may not be easy to convince them that “More Care is not necessarily Better Care” — or that, in fact, higher quality and lower costs go hand in hand.
But lately we have been learning that “more” is not as desirable as we once thought. Think about it: Larger Portions, Larger Cars, Larger Homes — and Larger Utility Bills. Not to mention Jumbo Mortgages. (See last Sunday’s New York Times touting “The New Trophy Home, Small and Ecological.” Raise your hand if you remember Jerry Brown.
What’s Wrong with Emanuel’s Plan
After writing a post about what the pro’s of Emanuel’s plan, Ezra Klein promised that he would follow up with a post about the cons. A few days passed, and finally, he posted “The Case Against.”
In the very first paragraph, he sums it up: “The case against comes down to basically one word: Politics.”
Klein continued: “The other day, I said, ‘when evaluating health plans, a good rule of thumb is this: The closer it is to our current system, the less it does to control costs. The farther it is, the more it does.’ [Emanuel’s] voucher plan is pretty far from our current system, and does a lot to control costs. The flip side of that rule is that the farther a health care plan is from our system, the more it does to control costs, the harder it is to pass through the United States Senate.”
Exactly. It’s not the American people who object to talk about controlling costs. Senators squirm at the very idea — because they know what the lobbyists would say. Voters might want lower prices, but lobbyists want higher profits. And Congressmen don’t like to find themselves caught between a rock and a hard place.
Overall, Klein suggests, Guaranteed HealthCare Access represents excellent public policy, but politically, it would be a very hard sell.
“If we lived in a sensible polity, and legislative politics were basically good-faith negotiations between public-spirited, responsible Democrats and public-spirited, responsible Republicans, I’d imagine that we’d end up with something a whole lot like this plan,” Klein acknowledged. “But we don’t live in that polity. And while this plan makes a lot of policy sense, it’s harder to fit it into a political system that’s rarely interested in what makes sense.”
Klein does point to some problems: Americans might be very reluctant to give up the employer-based system they know for an unknown. (Though many chafe at the fact that their need for insurance limits their employment choices.) Klein also notes that “Serious up-front cost controls mean you’re ripping a lot of profit from the system. Which means a lot of stakeholder opposition. … This is “ not to be underestimated,” he adds, “and a clear political strategy has to exist for overcoming these forces.” Klein also would also like to see a public-sector insurance plan competing with the private insurers. I agree — this is one of the strongest parts of Obama’s plan.
Klein does leave a window open: “If Emanuel and Fuchs were able to convince a Senator to offer it as legislation, and then it turned out to get a lot of cosponsors and hit a nerve, that would be different. But until that happens, it’s just a very sensible plan that clarifies exactly how far we are from a very sensible political system.”
I’d add that, with the right political backing from the right Senators, elements of Emanuel’s proposal could be blended with Obama’s plan. I’m not suggesting that Congress should rubber-stamp an Emanuel-Fuchs-Obama plan in the first six months of the next administration. I am suggesting that progressive reformers should take a close look at Guaranteed Healthcare Access and see what elements they might use. Begin with the vouchers—which insure equality—and the VAT tax, which could insulate health care reform from Congress and Lobbyists. Think about the high administrative costs that accompany employer-based insurance.
Finally, talk about cost control. As I’ve said before, runaway health care inflation is the elephant in the middle of the room. Try to ignore it and we’ll wind up with an unaffordable, unsustainable system that pleases no one—except, perhaps, those who feed at the health care trough.
Maggie Mahar is an award winning journalist and author. A frequent contributor to THCB, her work has appeared in the New York Times, Barron’s and Institutional Investor. She is the author of Money-Driven Medicine: The Real Reason Why Healthcare Costs So Much, an examination of the economic forces driving the healthcare system. A fellow at the Century Foundation, Maggie is also the author the increasingly influential HealthBeat blog, one of our favorite healthcare reads, where this piece first appeared.
Categories: Uncategorized
This is a wonderful discussion Thank you The plan is not perfect but is backed by thoughtful people If we added to these ideas the concepts of reducing the burdensome machinery of E and M coding and copays and billing it has great potential
I am a family doc in Maine .Self employed Solo . NO STAFF.
Work with a unusual highly driven bunch of docs going after both quality and patient experience of care. Measure my outcomes.
1. Not sure about the research that shows that employed docs deliver better quality ? Better quality comes from agreement /standardization of best practices That entails leadership at the local level and most leadership locally is about productivity
Quality care does not necessarily come with employment of docs This is not known to me- as much is not known to o f course I am a working doc.:)
2 This plan has been known to me for awhile and has much good in it. But copays are always tricky as is the comment posted above that patients must bear some financial risk .Risk is an insurance industry word that should not apply to sick people in search of care. Copays as i understand it , INHIBIT people from getting care. I am pretty sure there is good research that says every time you make a patient pay up front you reduce the likelihood of them seeking care Like it or not this is true.
Someone always comes along who says Well! Those patients ,they have cellphones and cigarettes they can pay 3.00 for a visit .This misunderstands the people who come for care on more levels than this small doc can type, and fragments us .We go from doctors delivering care to parties taking sides against each other. Very very bad for care.
The plan as suggested Ithink leaves in place some things that docs find onerous and/ or is unclear about others:
Primary care needs to be paid across a continuum -not piece meal visit by visit We need reduced administrative burdens or pay us for such burdens.Those of us doing open access scheduling e- visits , phone follow up ,email etc are oft doing it at our own expense becasue it is the right thing to do .The main reason docs take employment is for the paycheck not for consolation or leadership of quality.
Primary care is dying and the future plans adopted in this country need to be very careful about delineating how we are paid and how our work in structured so that we can coordinate care.
This is a wonderful discussion Thank you The plan is not perfect but is backed by thoughtful people If we added to these ideas the concepts of reducing the burdensome machinery of E and M coding and copays and billing it has great potential
I am a family doc in Maine .Self employed Solo . NO STAFF.
Work with a unusual highly driven bunch of docs going after both quality and patient experience of care. Measure my outcomes.
1. Not sure about the research that shows that employed docs deliver better quality ? Better quality comes from agreement /standardization of best practices That entails leadership at the local level and most leadership locally is about productivity
Quality care does not necessarily come with employment of docs This is not known to me- as much is not known to o f course I am a working doc.:)
2 This plan has been known to me for awhile and has much good in it. But copays are always tricky as is the comment posted above that patients must bear some financial risk .Risk is an insurance industry word that should not apply to sick people in search of care. Copays as i understand it , INHIBIT people from getting care. I am pretty sure there is good research that says every time you make a patient pay up front you reduce the likelihood of them seeking care Like it or not this is true.
Someone always comes along who says Well! Those patients ,they have cellphones and cigarettes they can pay 3.00 for a visit .This misunderstands the people who come for care on more levels than this small doc can type, and fragments us .We go from doctors delivering care to parties taking sides against each other. Very very bad for care.
The plan as suggested Ithink leaves in place some things that docs find onerous and/ or is unclear about others:
Primary care needs to be paid across a continuum -not piece meal visit by visit We need reduced administrative burdens or pay us for such burdens.Those of us doing open access scheduling e- visits , phone follow up ,email etc are oft doing it at our own expense becasue it is the right thing to do .The main reason docs take employment is for the paycheck not for consolation or leadership of quality.
Primary care is dying and the future plans adopted in this country need to be very careful about delineating how we are paid and how our work in structured so that we can coordinate care.
This is a wonderful discussion Thank you The plan is not perfect but is backed by thoughtful people If we added to these ideas the concepts of reducing the burdensome machinery of E and M coding and copays and billing it has great potential
“There’s nothing progressive about wasting 20% to 50% of the dollars spent on health care.”
Shouldn’t our goal as a society, and as the human race, be to make everyone’s life as healthy and pleasant as possible? If that means spending 20% of our dollars on health care, then so be it! Our priorities should be to ensure everyone has enough to eat and drink, has a safe place to live/sleep, etc. If we are serious about giving everyone the best life possible, then let’s actually do it.
I wonder what % of our dollars are spent on weaponry? Is that % growing at a rate that outraces the GDP?
The health care issue hits me the hardest with drug costs; My union has not been able to keep my CoPay as low as in the past so I have had to seek alternatives. One site I have been using is http://www.OPTIMIZERx.com . They have been helping me out finding me rebates, trial offers and the best thing is that it is totally free. Check it out we all need this kind of help today.
One “con” I see in a voucher plan that still relies on multiple insurers is the ability of industry to consolidate to reduce competition. The initial years when the “800+” insurance providers are “competing” may initially work in favor of the premium payer but as the industry realizes competition does not mean profits look for a few very large players controlling the marketplace so that their stock prices keep rewarding investors at the expense of premium payers. I like the dedicated tax and the idea of a, “if you want more, pay more” concept but wonder if a VAT tax is the way to do it, especially when the ecomony is already hammering middle income tax payers. Why not just have a heathcare adder on your income tax return. And a VAT tax on what, services as well as products? It will take a lot of convincing to assure voters there will be an offset saving. I don’t see State governments giving us the savings as they are already under the gun budget wise. What makes this all the more difficult now is the general rate of inflation without healthcare costs, telling people they need to spend more taxes, not less, will need a bigger backbone and more vision than politicians have. But there has to be a move off first base somewhere or we will just get closer to crisis where political decisions will be even worse. Right now McCain and Obama are trying to outdo each other on who’s the most bland centrist – don’t look for any innovative ideas from either of them.
Tcoyote–
I believe you that there is consolidation in places like Maine and Iowa, but in the states with the greatest number of doctors, this has not yet been the case. (N.Y. California N.J. etc. etc.)
But reserach suggests that we will be better off if more doctors go to work for hospitals, on salary, rather than staying in private practice fee-for-service. There is less over-treatment, and most importantly, there is more collaboration among doctors and between the doctor and the hospital. This means that care is better co-ordinated. These days, medicine must be a team sport.
Patients being about to “choose” among 60 or 70 or 200 doctors in private practice isn’t worth much unless they have a way to choose the doctor who can best meet their medical needs. They can’t because it’s impossible to “grade” individual doctors in a meaningful way. A group of non-compliant or seriously ill patients can skew the results, making an “A” doctor look like a “C” doctor.
The only way to correct for those disortions is to look at an enormous group of patients treated by a veyr large group of doctors and a hospital. (For example, the Cleveland Clinic.) Only then can you measure–and reward–better outcomes, publish the results, and give
patients some meangingful information about quality.
Finally, the days of the solo practiioner or small
group practice are coming to an end for economic reasons.
The cost of real estate, the cost of healthcare information technology and the cost of skilled assistants wiil make it all but impossible for solo or
small group pracices to make it in the future.
And, for patients, this is a good thing. Our system is too fragmented. We need mroe efficient, better co-ordinated care.
Back in the real world, doctors are disappearing into hospitals at a remarkable rate.
As private medical practice collapses, not only primary care physicians but general surgeons, cardiologists, etc. are appearing at the back door of the hospital ceo wanting in. Even relatively well off docs do not have the free cash to recruit in a tightening physician market.
The primary care consolidation is already quite far along. 70% or better of the primary care docs in Maine (which is dominated by two large hospital systems) are employed by hospitals. Comparable numbers of the FP’s in Iowa. It’s happening very quickly. So hospital consolidation is being followed very quickly by physician consolidation. Markets are rolling up. There aren’t going to be a lot of choices.
MedPac has done a good job, but look closer and you will see that the major interest groups, particularly teaching hospitals and specialty physicians, are well represented and advocated for. It is more efficient than lobbying because they are directly at the table. It isn’t a bad model, but it will not scale up to actually make Medicare policy. Precisely its advisory character is what has insulated it from the money part of politics. The big money knows where the real decisions are made. When it is no longer advisory, MedPac’s disinterested thoughtfulness will evaporate quickly.
Will read the book, but there is a bigger gap between theorists and what’s actually happening in the real world than perhaps you appreciate.
Anon–\
Thanks for lightening the conversation.
I’d love to see it get back on track.
I’m hoping that other people who are truly interested in health care reform will weigh in.
On a lighter note since a number of Americans seem to believe that the Bible should be used for the basis of public policy making in an AOL poll the other day, maybe we should structure emerging wellness programs around the idea of preventing two deadly sins – sloth and gluttony. If you largely eliminated these two, you wouldn’t have to worry about health care costs as much.
Tcoyote and Fard–
Thanks for your comments.
Tcoyote:
You might want to read the book before dismissing the idea out of hand. (Btw, the book has gotten very good reviews from the Financial Times and Newsweek.) And Matthew has pointed out that Emanuel’s idea is based directly on Enthoven’s thinking . . .
As to who sets the prices: that would be done by a National Health Board which oversees the 12 regional boards. (These boards are funded by the VAT so they are not at the mercy of Congress for yearly appropriations. As Emanuel describes them the boards will be nominated by the President and confirmed by the Senate for fixed, long, staggered terms which can be renewed only once.)
In many ways the board reminds me of the Medicare Payment Advisory Commission (MedPac).The Commission has 17 members (appointed by the Comptroller General of the General Accounting Office) who bring a wide range of expertise in the financing and delivery of health care services. The Commission is supported by a full-time executive director and a staff of approximately 30 analysts. Analysts typically have backgrounds in economics, health policy, public health or medicine.
MedPac’s reports and recommendations have been consistently excellent, but since it is only an advisory board, Congress is free to ignore them–which it has– though now that Medicare is running out of money, Congress may have to listen . .
Under Emanuel’s plan, the Board would adjust how much providers were paid in different parts of the country based on cost-of-living in different regions. Most likely it also would raise payments for services that it considered most valuable in terms of promoting more efficient, higher quality care (preventive servcies, chronic disease management, palliative care) while reducing payments for care that is only marginally effective.
The evidence produced by the Institute for Technology and Outcomes Assessment would drive the board’s decisions.
In order to cover the required comprehensive benefits within the budget (only VAT money would be used to fund healthcare) insurers would have to experiment with more efficient ways to pay providers. Fee-for-service encourages unncessary often redundant treatments, and virtually everyone agrees that we need to find a better way.
Emmanuel assumes that insurers would try to find better ways to pay for “quality,” not “quantity” since they would be held accountable for the quality of care that their networks of doctors and hospitals provide (see below.)
Presumably insurers would experiment with pay more for better outcomes, as well as “bundling” payments to doctors and hospitals, who care for a particular patient
.Insurers would have to report patient outcomes to their regional board and that infomation would be published. If an insurers’ outcomes were consistently below the norm they would lose market share and would ultimately be out of the system. So they would be motivated to improve quality of care
MedPac (the Medicare Payment Commission that advises
Congress) has made some very good suggestions in its recent reports (issued in March and June of each year.)
Up until now, as noted above, Congress has ignored those suggestions. But as someone in the Senate said recently, what we really need is “MedPac with teeth”–right now MedPac can only recommend, what if it could implement?
The members of the MedPac commission are very intelligent and. on the whole, don’t seem swayed by lobbyists. Emmanuel’s board could be “MedPac with teeth.”
Other countries have done this. There is no reason why we can’t too.
Finally, when you talk about provider consolidation, I take it you are talking about hospitals? Doctors haven’t consolidated in most parts of the country.
Reserach shows that when hospitals consolidate prices are no higher than in areas where there are more hospitals. One would think that more hospitals would equal more competition and lower prices.
But that isn’t the case. (In the health care market, competition just doesn’t work the way it does in other markets.)
In any case, the national board would be setting prices for hospital services too.
Fard– I went to your site and I agree. The number of Americans who are “underinsured” is spiraling. Many of them have something called “health insurance” but that doesn’t mean they receive health care. Thanks to high
deductibles, co-pays and holes in “Swiss Cheese” policies they either aren’t covered or can’t afford to use the coverage.
So they put off getting needed treatment. Those who favor high deductibles and co-pays say that they force patients to pay attention to price when deciding whether or not to seek care. This is true–but this doesn’t mean that patients will make the right choices, and avoid unnecessary over-priced care while seeking out necessary, fairly-priced care.
Reserach shows that when there is a co-pay or deductible, women don’t go for mammograms and Vets don’t enter smoking cessation clinics. . .
What I like about Emanuel’s voucher system is that it entitles everyone to the same rich menu of necessary, effective carewi–th the menu constantly updated by the Institute for Techology and Outcomes Assessment as it learns more about which treatments are most effective for patient who fit a particular profile. Right now, most of the informatoin we have about how effective a treatment is comes for the manufacturer or those who have a patient on the procedure, and it’s far from objective.
The plan is unAmerican. It’s fascist. The fascists of Italy, Nazi Germany, Communist Russia and the FDR Administration would have loved this top down plan that aggregates power over health insurance and health care in the hands of bureaucrats unaccountable to Congress or the American people.
Jonah Goldberg’s “Liberal Fascism, the secret history of the American left from Mussolini to the Politics of Meaning,” is an incredibly well documented and scholarly history of liberalism in America, which is basically American fascism.
The above article reflects a total fascist mind set. Goldberg defines fascism:
“Fascism is a religion of the state. It assumes the organic unity of the body politic and longs for a national leader [Obama, McCain] attuned to the will of the people. It is totalitarian in that it views everything as political and holds that any action by the state is justified to achieve the common good. It takes responsibility for all aspects of life, including our health and well-being, and seeks to impose uniformity of thought and action, whether by force or through regulation and social pressure. Everything, including the economy and religion, must be aligned with its objectives. Any rival identity is part of the ‘problem’ and therefore is defined as the enemy. I will argue that contemporary American liberalism embodies all of these aspects of facism.”
See http://www.liberal-fascism.com.
While it’s politically incorrect to point out the fascist heritage of a political proposal such as the one we’re discussing here, it also is intellectually corrupt to ignore the nature of the proposal and what it means to American freedom.
What the proposal ignores is not delivered by a “system.” It is delivered by competitors in numerous health care and health insurance markets. We live in a republic, not a dictatorship, and states and municipalities have roles in delivering health care as do thousands of private businesses.
Advocates of universal coverage delivered under the auspices of 12 regional health boards are saying that they want to enslave health care workers. They want to tell those workers how and when to deliver care and at specified wages and fees. We have that in Medicare and Medicaid today, and those markets are notoriously distorted and dysfunctional.
The “elminate administrative costs” crowd wants to run the rail roads on time, totally eliminate consumer choice and redistribute income. This makes no sense and won’t be accepted by Americans.
It’s not providers and their lobbyists who will discourage this kind of fascism, by the way. The Clinton plan was defeated by consumers and voters who didn’t trust politicians to provide health insurance or health care. (Note the ignorance shown in the proposal. Insurers don’t deliver care, don’t control quality and basically don’t know how to measure quality.)
Bottomline, imo, is that an Obama win with a larger Democratic Party majority in Congress will enable the fascists to pass a lot of their programs, but I don’t think they’ll be able to totally nationalize health care insurance and health care providers as outlined here. The Dems will abuse their power and lose a chunk of it in the 2010 elections. Enactment of socialized medicine will be such an abuse of the power that seems to be within the Dems’ grasp.
Maggie:
Interesting take on an issue that is of critical importance. In an era of runaway inflation, high medical costs are becoming a much more visible problem for many Americans. After all, if you are supposed to have insurance, but can’t take advantage of it, that gets one just a little bit annoyed. See my take on your thoughts here: http://tinyurl.com/6ynfno.
What Emmanuel describes simply isn’t insurance: rich benefit package, no economic risk to the patient, same price, guaranteed issue. It’s the “Golden Cornucopia” health plan with a direct pipeline to a gigantic pile of tax dollars.
Insulates providers from lobbyists, my ass. Who administers the global budget, anyhow? Who sets the rules for how the VAT is disbursed, the Supreme Court, the Fed? Give me a break, people.
Competing on quality through care networks somehow assumes a limitless ability to recombine providers into networks. Providers already have taken the guesswork out of it: there are only going to be one or two choices in all but the very largest markets, thanks to unchallenged mergers and consolidations. The care delivery system has already pre-empted the central dynamic in this plan through overtly anti-competitive action.
“Progressives” shouldn’t forget what health cost really is: it’s provider/supplier INCOMES. 80% of health costs are people and what those people are paid. Fail to put pressure on costs and you leave absurd “gold rush” level compensation in place for a fat, unresponsive industry. Unfortunately, Emmanuel doesn’t advance the health reform “debate” five feet. Another 50 thousand foot health plan from the dreamers. Roll over, Enthoven. . .